Currency Board Complications: The AEL Model
for
Department of Economics
9 February 1998
1. Doubting the
Classical Currency Board
Currency
boards originated in British colonies in the 19th century and seem to be
enjoying a revival since the 1980s (Hanke, Jonung and Schuler 1993; Schwartz 1993; Williamson 1995).
Present members of the "camp" include
A classical currency board issues notes and coins with 100% foreign reserves backing at a fixed exchange rate. The exchange rate of broader money is supposedly anchored at the same level because of two processes. The first is the specie-flow mechanism, just like under the gold standard. An outflow of capital would contract the money supply, push up the interest rates, and induce a counter-flow. The whole chain of events would automatically take place, within a short time horizon and without any government intervention.
In a modern and open financial economy, this presumed balance of payments mechanism is far from being reliable in the presence of expectations and uncertainty. Higher interest rates may not induce a counterflow of capital, if the exchange rate itself is in doubt. Exchange rate risk means that an interest rate premium is required, and higher interest rates might be interpreted as a sign of weakness, even leading to a vicious circle. The simultaneous occurrence of high interest rates and plunging exchange rates during the East Asian crisis is a case in point.
Therefore, there is the need for the second mechanism of the currency board: arbitrage that technically binds the exchange rate. Since a currency board has foreign reserves that cover at least 100 % of cash in circulation, if the market exchange rate weakens from the official rate, people can convert their bank deposits into cash, go to the currency board to exchange the cash into foreign currency at the stronger official rate, and then sell the foreign currency in the market, fetching an arbitrage profit. Cash arbitrage appeals to the self-interest of market participants. The selling pressure on the foreign currency will bring the market exchange rate back to the level of its official counterpart.
It is
claimed that, with the two "stabilizers", the currency board system
has had a "perfect record" of exchange rate stability. According to
Steve Hanke, "since the first currency board was
installed in
The
October 1997 attack on the currency of Hong Kong, the only territory in East
Asia adopting a currency board system (other than tiny Brunei), might have
jeopardized the prospect of the "perfect record".
A clear
lesson from the episode is that the
2. Modernizing
the Arbitrage Mechanism
A second,
perhaps more important, lesson is that cash arbitrage is hopeless in defending
a currency board regime in the modern context. In a banking
system with fractional cash reserves, allowing depositors to covert deposits
into cash for the sake of obtaining arbitrage profits is a hazardous business.
The cash base in any financial economy has been mercilessly diminishing. By the
end of 1997, the
Worse still, a cashless society is widely predicted to arrive some time in the 21st century. How would then a currency board be able to fix its exchange rate through cash arbitrage?
The whole picture would of course be dramatically changed if arbitrage can be performed effectively without involving cash, e.g. through electronic transfer instructions. This however requires some important institutional changes. For a start, the coverage of foreign exchange reserves must go beyond the cash base.
Hanke, Jonung and Schuler (1993,
p.5) observe that "in some cases" a currency board "issues
deposits" fully backed by foreign reserves, and in their recommended
"model constitution" for a currency board in
Neither Hanke, Jonung and Schuler (1993) nor Balino and Enoch have highlighted the operational differences between a CBA that guarantees the convertibility of only notes and coins and one that guarantees the convertibility of the total of banking reserves with it. In fact, there are significant implications, particularly with regard to arbitrage efficiency and the stability of the exchange rate.
Tsang (
A hypothetical example will illustrate how arbitrage can be done electronically, without involving cash or bank notes. Suppose we are in a country where the domestic currency, called peso, is pegged to the US dollar at parity under the convertible reserves scheme similar to the AEL model. Every bank then has no choice but to quote the official rate of 1 peso per US dollar. Suppose Bank A deviates and quotes an exchange rate of 1.1 peso. Bank B can sell US$1 million (or much larger amounts) to Bank A for 1.1 million peso, asking A to transfer the peso to B's account at the central bank. (B would of course transfer US$1 million to A's account there). The central bank is ready to convert the peso into US$1.1 million for Bank B, which then fetches an arbitrage profit of US$100,000. A, on the other hand, suffers a loss of 100,000 peso as its US$1 million at the central bank is worth only 1 million peso. If Bank A remains unrepentant, every other bank would be getting at it.
No cash movements are involved, as the central bank plays the role of clearing the arbitrage transactions between the two banks (Tsang, 1997). In the above example, the central bank's foreign reserves would be reduced by US$100,000, only if Bank A is foolish enough to accept a correspondent fall (100,000 peso) in its assets.
In reality,
under this "convertible reserves" system, no banks would dare to
deviate in quoting exchange rates. They are bound by the rule of the game
to quote the official exchange rate, within a very narrow buying and selling
spread that truly reflects petty transaction cost, or they will immediately be
hit by their fellow bankers. In the end, no actual arbitrage needs to take
place, and the central bank is in no fear of losing any foreign reserves.2
As arbitrage activities are settled by accounting instructions through telephone calls and other electronic means, the transaction cost is reduced to an absolute minimum. This arrangement for "cashless" arbitrage is superior not only to the cash-based arbitrage mechanism under the classical currency board, but also to gold-point arbitrage where physical shipment of gold bullion was required (Officer 1989, 1993).
3. The AEL
Model for
On the basis
of the RTGS infrastructure, it is a modest step to set up a system under which
every bank has a direct reserve account with the HKMA. One top of the normal
clearing balances, the HKMA could ask each bank to submit an equivalent amount
of US dollar to it for obtaining notes from the NIBs.3 Concurrently
or alternatively, the HKMA might impose a deposit reserve requirement on the
banks. To overcome resistance from the banking sector, the ratio, which could
be interpreted as a "financial tax", should be as small as possible.
The idea is not to tax the banks, but to ensure that there is suitable
liquidity in the reserve account to minimize any possible impact on the
interest rate. As explained above, if the system works, no actual arbitrage
needs to take place and the spot exchange rate will be fixed around the
official rate. In that situation of benign equilibrium, the deposit reserve
ratio may even be set at zero.4
At US$92.8
billion at the end of 1997, Hong Kong’s foreign exchange reserves were the
third largest in the world (after
4. Efficiency
Risk, Systemic Risk and Exit Cost
Although the
spot exchange rate is "fixed", the forward rate is not so
automatically. Local interest rates could still be higher than those of the
foreign counterpart, along with weak forward exchange rates. The reason may be
that market participants are not sure whether the convertible reserves system
can really fix the spot rate. In other words, there is an "efficiency risk"
and a risk premium is demanded. However, over time the fixation of the spot
rate should lead to the return of confidence, and convergence in
domestic-foreign interest rates and spot-forward exchange rates would take
place as people engage in interest arbitrage and capital inflow exceeds
outflow. That has been occurring in
However, that convergence has not been perfect. This is due to the existence of "systemic risk". In other words, although market participants observe the "fixed-ness" of the spot rate, they are not sure that the "perfect" system that is working so well will not be abandoned in the future, perhaps not because of its own faults, but as a result of other political and economic factors. Any one familiar with the political situation in these three countries understands why some people at least might be nervous, justifiably or otherwise, about the possibility of coup d'etat or external invasion. Moreover, no matter how good an arbitrage mechanism is in anchoring the exchange rate, whether a fixed rate regime is optimal for the economy in the long run is always a controversial issue.
Governments in
the three countries have tried to contain the market perception of systemic
risk by legal means (Tsang,
In the case
that
Enshrining the
link in law may go some way in further reducing systemic risk and lead to an
even higher degree of interest rate and exchange rate convergence. In any case,
the convergence can never be perfect as the law itself is still open to some
residual doubts. Moreover, it will actually increase the "dismounting
cost" or the "exit cost" of the link, in case it is deemed
optimal to abolish the fixed rate regime and re-float the
This also
applies to any scheme under which the HKMA issues insurance instruments (e.g.
put options) to market participants to foster confidence that the link rate of
7.80 will not be changed. The basic idea is "to put the money where the
mouth is". If the HKMA devalues the
Without an effective currency (or exchange rate) arbitrage mechanism such as the AEL model, insurance instruments alone may not be able to fix the link because there will always be market participants and speculators who are not allotted the put options. The ability of the HKMA to issue insurance coverage is obviously not unlimited. The relative strength of holders of put options versus non-holders is difficult to predict in the globalized financial market. The non-holders may decide to have a go at the link. We will then be back to the problem of "efficiency risk".
If an effective arbitrage mechanism is in place to bind the spot exchange rate (and hence to eliminate the efficiency risk), insurance instruments may help to reduce systemic risk. Their effectiveness will however depend on the insured amount offered to the market. If the amount is small, it will not add much to the defence of the link. If the amount is large, the exit cost (in terms of compensations to holders of the instruments) will escalate. One must note that the exit cost will eventually be borne by the local tax-payers.
Overall, the
Notes:
References
Balino, Tomas and Charles Enoch (1997) "Currency Board Arrangements: Issues and Experiences," IMF Occasional Paper, No. 151, August.
Bennett, Adam G.G. (1993) "The Operation of the Estonian Currency Board," IMF Staff Papers, 40 (2), June, 451-470.
Bennett, Adam G.G. (1994) "Currency Boards: Issues and Experiences," IMF Papers on Policy Analysis and Assessment, PPAA/94/18.
Hanke, Steve H., Lars Jonung and Kurt Schuler
(1993) Russian Currency and Finance,
Officer, Lawrence H. (1989) "The Remarkable Efficiency of the Dollar-Sterling Gold Standard, 1890-1906," Journal of Economic History, 49 (1), 1-41.
Officer, Lawrence H. (1993) "Gold-point Arbitrage and Uncovered Interest Arbitrage under the 1925-1931 Dollar-Sterling Gold Standard," Explorations in Economic History, 30 (1), 98-127.
Schwartz, Anna J. (1993) "Currency Boards: Their Past, Present and Possible Future Role," Carnegie-Rochester Conference on Public Policy, 39, 147-93.
Tsang, Shu-ki (1984) "On
the Cash-based Fixed Exchange Rate System," in The
Tsang, Shu-ki (
Tsang, Shu-ki (1996b) "The Linked Rate System: through 1997 and into the 21st Century," in Ngaw Mee-kau and Li Si-ming (ed.), The Other Hong Kong Report 1996, Hong Kong: The Chinese University Press, chapter 11.
Tsang, Shu-ki (1997) "Currency Board the Answer to Rate Stability," Hong Kong Standard, 31 October 1997.
Williamson, John (1995) What Role for Currency Boards? US: Institute for International Economics.